Opinon: Planning for a brighter future

Yesterday, I set out the indictment of our current land-use planning system, which has created a housing crisis, is stifling our economy and leading to damaging environmental outcomes. That’s fairly widely acknowledged. It is far less simple to propose an alternative, but below I hope to outline some possible principles as mechanisms for a better planning system that empowers individuals and communities rather than bureaucrats and politicians.

The first thing we need to do is to restore the principle that those who suffer the secondary effects of development are compensated. The original Town and Country Planning Act (1947) did contain provision for compensation, but this was deleted by the Conservatives in the 1950s, and when Labour got back into power compensation had morphed into a way of channelling money to local authorities, rather than those who actually lose out.

This is an anomaly, because the compensation of those hurt by one’s actions is a general principle of law: if a factory emits pollution that damages your property, you are entitled to compensation; why should the same not take place when the factory is built and it impacts upon the amenity of your home?

The effect of removing the requirement to compensate third parties is that it makes NIMBYism rational. If one has nothing to gain from a neighbouring development, even the smallest loss is reason to fight. Once neighbours can expect compensation, it becomes possible for a price to be set on amenity: if the benefit to the developer is greater than the perceived loss among the neighbours, the developer can buy the right to develop from them.

Creating a market in development rights is crucial to enable us to weigh the subjective values that people place on various goods: for example, the extent to which we value green space, more housing, better infrastructure, new places of work etc.  This would not do away with planning, but it would devolve planning to local people and create an efficient land use planning system.

I discuss a number of possibilities in the report. One is to give much more discretion to local authorities, encouraging the use of zoning and tradable development rights rather than councillors taking executive decisions. However, I think we should go further – the bureaucracy of Whitehall should not merely be replaced with – the bureaucracy of the Town Hall. One alternative is devolution to individuals and small communities by the creation of Proprietary Communities, which are able to restrict, permit, buy and sell development rights based on the priorities of local people.

This will undoubtedly lead to more development, but it will also lead to the right balance of development and conservation. Indeed, conservationists may be among the great beneficiaries of this system. Firstly, conservation groups could buy development rights for the express purpose of preventing development, enabling their subjective values to be weighed against those who wish to see land developed. Secondly, local systems could be designed so that development in environmentally sensitive areas is explicitly linked to promoting conservation (as has happened in the US in Kern County and the New Jersey Pinelands, for example). Thirdly, conservationists would retain the ability to take out covenants on pieces of land to prevent future development – a practice that has waned since the nationalisation of development rights in 1947. In fact, developers themselves may take out covenants on neighbouring land, so that buyers could be confident that amenity will be protected once they’ve moved in.

The key lesson, however, as that what we need is pluralism, experimentation and competition. It would be hubris to assume that we know which approach to land-use planning is the best – or even to assume that what is best in London is best in Leeds, or Leamington, or Little Haven. The best solution to the planning problem is not to deliberately design a land-use planning system but to allow various systems to develop and to explore which ones yield the best outcomes. For this we need to remove government from the equation and let an entrepreneurial process of experimentation and discovery take place.

Planning is essential if we are to enjoy a bright future. The question is not whether we plan, the question is who plans, and how. As ever, individualism and pluralism – those two core features of liberalism – are the key to finding the best solutions.

Tom Papworth is Leader of the Liberal Democrat Group on the London Borough of Bromley, and sits on two plans committees. The  views expressed in this article are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of, and should not be attributed to, other Liberal Democrats, the party generally or the Bromley Council Group.

* Tom Papworth is a member of Waltham Forest Liberal Democrats

Read more by or more about or .
This entry was posted in Op-eds.
Advert

13 Comments

  • LondonLiberal 15th Mar '12 - 5:57pm

    @ Tom “Yesterday, I set out the indictment of our current land-use planning system, which has created a housing crisis, is stifling our economy and leading to damaging environmental outcomes. That’s fairly widely acknowledged.”

    er, no, it isn’t. that we have a housing crisis is certainly widely acknowledged, but that the cause of this is planning system, certainly isn’t. House prices rocketed partly because of a lack of supply, and partly because of far too easily available credit. why was there a lack of supply? well, it could have something to do with the state essentially stopping building any homes and an (as i say elsewhere) oligopolistic construction sector that places margin over volume. as we have discussed elsewhere, the planning system allows for lots of homes to be built, if locla people wish it, but democracy doesn’t incentivise that to happen. so it’s not planning, it’s people that are the problem. ripping upt he planning system and essentially saying build anything anywhere, as the NPPF signals, isn’t a clever solution to the problem.

    having said that, proper incentives to local people to accept new deleopment, and community land auctions, seem liek good ways forward.

  • Richard Dean 15th Mar '12 - 7:54pm

    Doesn’t much of the activity of planning happen BEFORE you get to a market for development rights? Put another way, to create tradeable development right in the first place, don’t you have to have a plan of what the right is to be? Or are you suggesting that a tradeable right to develop should not place any restriction on what can be developed?

    Would the right mean that local people will no longer have a say in what I can do? Can I buy a general right to develop in an area, then develop a factory pig farm whose odours and ethics enrage the nearby housing estate? Would I be allowed to build what peope consider to be an eyesore, if I have a development right?

  • ROB SHEFFIELD 15th Mar '12 - 8:18pm

    @London Liberal

    With folks such as you still in the party then there is hope for it in the medium term.

    I’m afraid that the short term impact on the party of the next few May local elections and the next general election is going to be down to neoliberals such as Tom. For Tom and co read Tony and co in the Labour party circa 1980-1985.

    It all sounds so logical: but on closer inspection (and smelling) you know what they are offering you !

  • Richard Dean 15th Mar '12 - 10:41pm

    How would I assign a monetary value to a development right if I did not know in advance what compensation I would need to pay for exercising it? Perhaps some fixed scale of compensation might need to come as part of the right?

  • LondonLiberal 16th Mar '12 - 10:19am

    @ Tom

    Thanks for your detailed responses. There are some facts which i hope we can agree on.

    1. The lack of a planning system in the 19th century and early 20th century did not produce decent housing, in sufficient quantity, for the populatin. One only has to look at the (now largely disappeared) slums of our cities to see how unsuccessfully housed we were as a nation.
    2. The housing boom of the 1920s and 30s – part of which was of course council housing – did produce large numbers of homes in often suburban settings at very cheap prices, and these were popular because people liked both these things.
    3. These ‘ribbon’ developments came at great cost to the environment, as their very low density required a relatively large area to be given over to them and their lack of critical mass meant heavy reliance on cars and a relative absence of street life.
    4. The TCPA in 1947 was partly motivated by the worry of the loss of all this land, partly because of lost agricultural output, and partly because of concerns of endless urban sprawl.
    5. Since the passing of the TCPA, our housing problems were not solved, and some old slums buildings were swept away only to creat new slums in modern buildings. With the best will in the world, a lot of new housing, mainly public but also some private, was of very low quality, design and social policy.
    6. These problems of quality, design and social poolicy were not a result of the planning system.
    7. We have never built enough homes, of sufficient quality and quantity, to house our population, pre- or post the 1947 TCPA. This suggests that it is not the TCPA that is the problem.

  • LondonLiberal 16th Mar '12 - 10:21am

    oops, 5 is meant to end: “With the best will in the world, a lot of new housing, mainly public but also some private, was of very low quality and design, and social policy made it worse.”

  • In the (southern) town where I live – there will shortly be a hosepipe ban. The big plot of land behind my house is owned by Glasgow city council pension fund, who will build a big office block on it. The town is full of empty office blocks, many built in the last 10 years, many owned by pension funds where trustees and fund managers presumeably have a tenuous grasp on what investments will produce returns.

    We need to actively create more jobs up north, where there is a surplus of water and housing. We need to encourage some pension money to flow into job creation and housing rather than empty office blocks. We need to build more housing specifically suitable for an aging population and for young workers.

  • Alistair, a valuable point, a town of empty office blocks and they build another.. along with all those empty warehouses on the edge of most towns. .. and the investors and bankers want us to similarly build loads of spare houses for the same reason.
    There is a confusion here, this idea of supply and demand, greater supply bringing down the price, might work with some commodities, but with property it certainly doesn’t. The price of property is related to the availability of finance, not the availability of property. Values rocketed when people could borrow 120% of value.. Owners of commercial property can borrow against the value of the property, even if it is standing empty, as they rely on the increase in values to get a return on their investment. An audit of vacant property in any town or city will show a truly shocking rate of vacancy in all sectors.
    Part of the answer to the homes crisis is to charge council tax on all residential property, no exemptions. If it has a roof on it the owner pays council tax, (any relief or subsidy required should be left to the benefit system to deal with) then owners of vacant property would be encouraged to either let or sell.

  • Alistair, a valuable point, a town of empty office blocks and they build another.. along with all those empty warehouses on the edge of most towns. .. and the investors and bankers want us to similarly build loads of spare houses for the same reason.
    There is a confusion here, this idea of supply and demand, greater supply bringing down the price, might work with some commodities, but with property it certainly doesn’t. The price of property is related to the availability of finance, not the availability of property. Values rocketed when people could borrow 120% of value.. Owners of commercial property can borrow against the value of the property, even if it is standing empty, as they rely on the increase in values to get a return on their investment. An audit of vacant property in any town or city will show a truly shocking rate of vacancy in all sectors.
    Part of the answer to the homes crisis is to charge council tax on all residential property, no exemptions. If it has a roof on it the owner pays council tax, (any relief or subsidy required should be left to the benefit system to deal with) then owners of vacant property would be encouraged to either let or sell.

Post a Comment

Lib Dem Voice welcomes comments from everyone but we ask you to be polite, to be on topic and to be who you say you are. You can read our comments policy in full here. Please respect it and all readers of the site.

To have your photo next to your comment please signup your email address with Gravatar.

Your email is never published. Required fields are marked *

*
*
Please complete the name of this site, Liberal Democrat ...?

Advert



Recent Comments

  • Helen Dudden
    The veterans are one sad fact of life. It's a 10 year waiting list for an accessible flat or home. Many are left losing limbs. Often a long stay in hospital ...
  • Roland
    @Simon “ I think the real lesson there for us is, if the UK ever gets a written constitution, make sure it can be changed and updated without too much difficu...
  • Suzanne Fletcher
    Hope that the issues in the important motion are able to be promoted far and wide beyond the Lib Dems, so they end up being put into practice. our Lib Dem parl...
  • Joseph Bourke
    This author writes Politicians of...
  • Steve Trevethan
    What is your definition of democracy?...